This is an educational resource based on the Wikipedia article on Proportionality for Solid Coalitions. Read the full source article here. (opens in new tab)

The Calculus of Consensus

An academic exploration of the Proportionality for Solid Coalitions (PSC) criterion, a key concept in understanding fairness in ranked electoral systems.

What is PSC? ๐Ÿ‘‡ Explore Quotas ๐Ÿ”ข

Dive in with Flashcard Learning!


When you are ready...
๐ŸŽฎ Play the Wiki2Web Clarity Challenge Game๐ŸŽฎ

Introduction to PSC

Defining Proportionality

Proportionality for Solid Coalitions (PSC) is a criterion used to evaluate the fairness of ranked voting systems, particularly those without explicit party lists. It adapts the fundamental concept of the quota rule to scenarios where voters directly support candidates, forming groups known as "solid coalitions."

Dummett's Contribution

This criterion was first articulated by the distinguished British philosopher and logician, Michael Dummett. His work sought to establish robust mathematical frameworks for assessing the proportionality of electoral outcomes, especially in systems where voter preferences are ranked.

Michael Dummett's extensive research in logic and philosophy extended into the field of social choice theory and electoral systems. His seminal work, "Voting Procedures," laid much of the groundwork for understanding the mathematical properties of various voting methods, including proportionality criteria like PSC.

Minimal Definition

PSC is considered a relatively minimal definition of proportionality. It primarily ensures that if a group of voters consistently ranks a specific set of candidates above all others (forming a solid coalition), then at least a proportional number of seats should be allocated to candidates from that set.

Understanding Solid Coalitions

The Essence of a Solid Coalition

In electoral systems that lack formal party lists, the concept of a "solid coalition" serves as the analogue to a political party. A solid coalition is defined as a group of voters who, when ranking candidates, consistently prefer any candidate within a particular set over any candidate not in that set.

Commitment and Preference

When voters are part of a solid coalition, they are considered to be "solidly supporting" or "solidly committed to" the candidates within that set. This implies a strong, unified preference structure among these voters for their chosen candidates.

Boundaries and Factions

Crucially, solid coalitions cannot arbitrarily cut across different factions or preference groups. For instance, on a political spectrum, moderate voters from the center-left and center-right might not form a single solid coalition if some center-right voters rank a far-right candidate higher than a center-left candidate. This segmentation is key to how PSC operates.

Quotas and PSC

Hare-PSC

The Hare-PSC criterion utilizes the Hare quota, calculated as the total number of voters () divided by the number of seats (), i.e., .

It mandates that if a solid coalition commands at least Hare quotas, then at least candidates from that coalition must be elected.

In the context of a single-winner election (), the Hare quota equals the total number of voters (). A solid coalition with Hare quota (i.e., all voters) is guaranteed to elect one candidate, making it equivalent to the unanimity criterion in single-winner elections.

Droop-PSC

Droop-PSC employs the Droop quota, calculated as the total number of voters () divided by the number of seats plus one (), i.e., .

This variant ensures that if a solid coalition commands at least Droop quotas, at least candidates from that coalition must be elected.

Droop-PSC is a generalization of the majority criterion. A significant advantage is that any solid coalition achieving a majority of votes is guaranteed to secure at least half of the available seats. However, this method can introduce a "seat bias," potentially favoring larger parties and disadvantaging smaller coalitions even if their combined vote share is substantial.

Related Methods

Several electoral methods are known to satisfy quota-proportional criteria, including PSC. Notable examples include the Expanding Approvals Rule, the Method of Equal Shares, and the widely used Single Transferable Vote (STV) system.

Advanced Concepts & Generalizations

Generalized and Inclusion PSC

Researchers Aziz and Lee have extended the PSC concept. They introduced Generalized PSC and Inclusion PSC, which are applicable even when voters employ "weak rankings" (allowing for indifference between candidates). Their Expanding Approvals Rule is noted for satisfying these more comprehensive versions of PSC.

Rank-PJR+

Brill and Peters proposed Rank-PJR+, another fairness property designed for weak rankings. This criterion specifically addresses coalitions that are only "partially solid." The Expanding Approvals Rule adheres to Rank-PJR+, whereas the Single Transferable Vote (STV) does not. Importantly, determining if a committee satisfies Rank-PJR+ can be achieved efficiently through polynomial-time computation.

Teacher's Corner

Edit and Print this course in the Wiki2Web Teacher Studio

Edit and Print Materials from this study in the wiki2web studio
Click here to open the "Proportionality For Solid Coalitions" Wiki2Web Studio curriculum kit

Use the free Wiki2web Studio to generate printable flashcards, worksheets, exams, and export your materials as a web page or an interactive game.

True or False?

Test Your Knowledge!

Gamer's Corner

Are you ready for the Wiki2Web Clarity Challenge?

Learn about proportionality_for_solid_coalitions while playing the wiki2web Clarity Challenge game.
Unlock the mystery image and prove your knowledge by earning trophies. This simple game is addictively fun and is a great way to learn!

Play now

Explore More Topics

Discover other topics to study!

                                        

References

References

  1.  D. R. Woodall: Monotonicity of single-seat preferential election rules. Discrete Applied Mathematics 77 (1997), p. 83รขย€ย“84.
  2.  Tideman N.: Collective Decisions and Voting. Ashgate Publishing Ltd, Aldershot, 2006, p. 268รขย€ย“269.
A full list of references for this article are available at the Proportionality for solid coalitions Wikipedia page

Feedback & Support

To report an issue with this page, or to find out ways to support the mission, please click here.

Disclaimer

Important Notice

This content has been generated by an Artificial Intelligence and is intended for educational and informational purposes only. It is based on publicly available data and may not be exhaustive or entirely up-to-date.

This is not professional advice. The information provided herein does not constitute expert advice in political science, mathematics, or electoral system design. Readers are encouraged to consult primary sources and qualified professionals for in-depth analysis and specific applications.

The creators of this page are not responsible for any errors or omissions, or for any actions taken based on the information provided.